American
companies fail to realize that no manufacturing industry can survive
on its own; not only is the whole of the manufacturing sector
greater than the sum of its parts, the parts without the whole will
equal zero... But surely these corporations are smarter than that,
they must have some plan to deal with a shrinking American market?
No. Advised by a class of professional economists who are trained to
explain why this is the best of all possible worlds as long as the
corporations can do whatever they want, blinded by greed and the
low-hanging fruit of greater profits from lower wages, no CEO will
think to do what Henry Ford did when he introduced the $5 day for
workers. Ford justified his largesse by pointing out that his
workers could now afford to buy his cars.
Clueless Turkeys
The travails of the U.S. automakers have drawn attention, however
fleeting, to the sorry state of U.S. manufacturing in general. The
U.S. auto industry is the latest in a string of U.S. industries that
were seen as pillars of the American economy, only to be submerged
by some mysterious process of inundation. High-tech manufacturing,
airplanes, computers and the like have succumbed to foreign
competition. Like turkeys who don’t notice that all of their
neighbors are being decapitated, American companies simply take note
that, once again, something is happening without stopping to figure
out if there are some larger forces at work. They fail to realize
that no manufacturing industry can survive on its own; not only is
the whole of the manufacturing sector greater than the sum of its
parts, the parts without the whole will equal zero.
The multinational corporations have bought into the idea that all
they have to do is pursue profit, by whatever means necessary, in
order to maximize both short-term and long-term profit and power.
Thus does the invisible hand replace an all-powerful God with a
flowing gray beard as the font of all that is good in the world, in
the faith-based world-view of economists and CEOs alike. But
unfortunately for both the corporate world and the U.S. economy,
there is a profound contradiction between the pursuit of short-term
profit and long-term viability.
Manufacturing is going off a cliff, and the middle class is not
far behind. When the middle class eviscerates, so will the main
market of U.S. multinational corporations, and all the President’s
military machinery will not be able to put that market back together
again. The well-laid plans of the Walmarts and Dells of this world
to make everything abroad and sell it at “home” will go up in smoke.
The multinational corporations think that their brand is their most
valuable asset, but Indians will buy from Indian companies,
Europeans will buy from European companies, and Chinese will buy
from Chinese companies. The thrill of buying American will be gone,
and so will the American multinationals. The invisible hand will
dump them into the dustbin of history.
But surely these corporations are smarter than that, they must
have some plan to deal with a shrinking American market? No. Advised
by a class of professional economists who are trained to explain why
this is the best of all possible worlds as long as the corporations
can do whatever they want, blinded by greed and the low-hanging
fruit of greater profits from lower wages, no CEO will think to do
what Henry Ford did when he introduced the $5 day for workers. Ford
justified his largesse by pointing out that his workers could now
afford to buy his cars.
Ford may not have been motivated by such far-sighted thoughts. He
may have been trying to put a gloss on the need to increase wages so
that the auto workers’ union would be undercut in its efforts to
unionize Ford. Except in rare cases, top managers do not give up
power unless the loss of decision-making is being forced down their
throats, as in unionization efforts in the 1930s or regulation in
the Progressive era or in the 1960s. When the corporations have
their way, as in the Bush/Reagan/Clinton era, they manage to shoot
themselves in the foot; NAFTA and Most Favored Nation status for
China were good for them in the short-term, not in the
long-term.
The industrial economy as an ecosystem
Destroying their market is one huge mistake; but there is
something even more fundamental going on here. Ford and G.M. are at
the top of the pyramid of the industrial system. If no man is an
island then huge industrial companies such as Ford and G.M. have to
be part of an entire continent. A former CEO of G.M. famously said
that what is good for G.M. is good for America; but what he didn’t
seem to understand is that what is good for the American
manufacturing base is good, indeed critical, for G.M.
A thriving economy that is based on a strong manufacturing base,
such as the U.S. used to be, is a kind of ecosystem. For instance,
in an ecosystem the plant-eating animals are dependent on the
plants, and the meat-eating animals are dependent on the
plant-eating animals and also indirectly on plants. In an economy,
different parts serve different functions, and these parts are
dependent on each other for survival and growth. The most important
relationship in an industrial economy is that between manufacturers
of final, consumed goods, and the machinery makers that provide the
factory machinery that is used to make those final goods.
Production machinery is the critical technology in an
industrial economy. Technological progress in production
machinery is the foundation of economic growth.
|
Production machinery is the critical technology in an industrial
economy. Technological progress in production machinery is the
foundation of economic growth. For example, the great strides in
computer power that we have witnessed over the last few decades are
the result of advances made in a particular class of production
machinery called semiconductor-making machinery. In the auto
industry, advances are dependent on various kinds of production
machinery. For example, machine tools are used to shape and cut the
metal pieces that make up most of a car. The more efficient the
machine tools are, and the better trained the workers are to use the
machine tools, the more precisely and quickly the car parts can be
made, thus improving the quality of the cars while decreasing the
cost.
The economy that stays together grows together
Paying unskilled workers less and less money is not the path to
economic growth. The engineers who design the machines and the
skilled production workers that make the machines are the people who
drive technological progress and economic growth.
If the machinery makers are disappearing, so eventually will the
makers of consumer goods, because the consumer goods companies will
not be able to obtain the best machinery in a timely manner. Since
the Japanese and German machinery makers are thriving, then the
German and Japanese consumer goods makers will get the latest and
greatest machinery before the Americans. Even when they get them,
the Americans will be at a great distance from their Japanese and
German suppliers.
Distance is important in a manufacturing economy. Manufacturers
need machinery makers and subcontractors that make the parts of the
finished product. They need suppliers of raw materials and
engineering consultants. All of these parts of an economy form a
cooperative system. The market is all about competition; production
is all about cooperation, and cooperation works best at close
quarters. The engineers need to “kick the tires” of the new
production processes they design. So while a market may be global,
production and the growth of production take place most efficiently
at continental or subcontinental distances. A system of production
is Japanese, or European, or Indian, or American – unless that
production is scattered to the four winds.
The U.S. multinational corporations have not only scattered their
production all across the planet, they have stood by while the
American machinery makers have been slaughtered by foreign
competition. Almost all of the remaining machine tool makers in the
U.S. are foreign owned. American engineers probably won’t visit the
factory that makes the goods they are designing or spend time
talking with the machinery makers’ engineers. Both of these
activities are crucial to a competent engineering class.
Losing the forest and the trees
No wonder Ford and G.M. are not known for innovation and quality.
Most observers blame the automakers’ decline on some kind of
historical inertia created by the dominance that these firms wielded
for so long. Certainly, that may have something to do with it. But
these observers miss the importance of the ecology of the industrial
system because they understand marketing and finance, not
production. Ford’s “world” cars are “bad” cars precisely because
they are “world”. Ford used to have a huge, centralized production
complex in River Rouge; if they really wanted to turn things around,
they would go back to their roots.
The industrial ecosystem that the car companies depend on needs
to be a certain minimal size. An economy needs a thick growth of
small machine shops and parts suppliers in order to support the
stands of large industrial companies such as Ford and G.M. A similar
principle has been discovered for natural ecosystems. For instance,
it has become clear that isolated parts of the Amazon rain forest
need to be of a certain minimum area if they are to sustain most of
its species. If the rain forest is left as a checkerboard of open
spaces alternating with rain forest, and the “checks” that are rain
forest are too small, then they will not be viable, and they will
eventually disappear.
The same principle holds for an industrial ecosystem. This is the
deepest problem for the car companies. They cannot hang on if they
are the only existing part of the manufacturing sector. Like a clump
of rainforest that is too small, they will eventually disappear,
unless they are reconnected to a large, thriving manufacturing
sector (see my previous article, “Before the economy hits the fan”,
for a discussion of how this can be done).
The general problems of the manufacturing sector have been caused
by three main problems: cheaper labor abroad, a
military-industrial-complex at home, and the transformation of
industrial firms into financial and marketing firms.
Expensive workers are good for you
The problem of cheaper labor abroad has been treated as if it was
a problem with no solution. There is simply nothing that can be
done, one reads, which means that the American working and middle
classes are doomed. If the cost of labor were indeed the main
consideration in production, this would be true. But it most
emphatically is not true.
The central factor in the creation of economic wealth and growth
is not the cheapness of labor, but the productive power of
machinery. If cheap labor were the road to international
competitiveness, then the oversupply of near-starving peasants in
China and India would have kept them at the top of the world food
chain for the last 1000 years. When England first invented
industrial machinery, it was able to use this advantage to conquer
one third of the world’s surface. When the English decided that
empire was more important than industry, the U.S. took over the
global economy, until it now, as the Mother country once did, has
become blinded by empire. But while it was on top, until the
mid-1970s, the U.S. consistently paid the highest industrial wages
in the world. According to the late Seymour Melman (he was a
professor of industrial engineering at Columbia University), this
fact actually helped the U.S. maintain its lead.
Melman’s concept that explained this unconventional wisdom he
called “alternative cost”. The basic idea is this: faced with high
labor costs, firm managers will be more willing to mechanize, that
is, use more machinery, and more sophisticated machinery, instead of
using labor. By using more, better machinery, they increase labor
productivity, which leads to higher wages, and they also stay at the
cutting edge of technology. Melman compared factories in England and
the U.S. after World War II, and found that the English, who paid
lower wages, were using more primitive equipment than the
Americans[1] .
Melman’s insight almost led to his dismissal from Columbia
University, because a conservative professor was offended by the
idea that the economy is improved by giving higher wages to workers;
the implication was that unions, by keeping wages high, were
actually good for the economy. An eminent statistical economist came
to his defense, and Melman was able to spend the next half-century
doggedly pursuing his conviction that less military and more labor
power was better for the economy. Melman also argued that the
productivity of capital is more important than the productivity of
labor. If machines are central to the process of production, and if
the machinery costs millions of dollars, then it makes sense that
keeping machinery running as efficiently as possible is more
important than the exact number of workers one is using or even how
much they are being paid[2] .
By driving down the price of labor in the U.S., manufacturing
companies have reversed the power of “alternative cost”. Instead of
using more and better machinery, they think it is easier or cheaper
to move production to a country such as China. As a result of this
process, the general level of competency of a country’s
manufacturing firms will decrease. Voila, the U.S. has a huge and
growing trade deficit in manufactured goods, because American
manufacturers are losing the competence to produce.
So higher wages were a competitive advantage, not a disadvantage
(not to be confused with comparative advantage, the subject of
another essay). The Chinese are not doing themselves any favors by
keeping their wages low either, because this will suppress their
technological progress.
A permanent war economy is a permanent drag on the economy
The other huge drag on American manufacturing competence has been
the large, and now even larger, military-industrial-complex. Melman
showed how this process works in gory detail. One way to demonstrate
a theory in social science is to pick a case study that combines
variables in a unique and useful way. If we want to see the effect
of the military on civilian work, then a good case study is to see
how defense companies perform when they attempt to do civilian work.
Melman showed that when defense firms have attempted to enter the
field of making buses, people movers, or subways, the products were
unusable. They were much too expensive, broke down all the time, did
not perform up to standards, and were not delivered on time.[3]
These are all hallmarks of incompetence, the kind that the
Soviets were famous for in their civilian sphere. The reasons are
similar; like the American military-industrial complex, the Soviet
economy was basically a system for producing military equipment.
When firms are not subject to the discipline of selling their
products in a market, then they do not learn how to make as much as
possible, as well as possible, for as cheap as possible. The U.S.
Pentagon is the American equivalent of the Soviet Gosplan, their
central planning agency.
This lack of competence spills out into the rest of the economy.
Because the military pays better salaries than the civilian sector,
many of the best and brightest scientists and engineers enter the
military sector and learn bad habits. Whole firms, or divisions of
firms, are also drawn to the higher profits guaranteed in the
military sector as moths to a light.
Corporate Chesire Cats
Even G.M. and Ford feed at the military trough. With the civilian
part of manufacturing firms looking over the oceans for cheap labor,
and the military side of manufacturing firms looking for lucrative
government contracts, when the consumer comes knocking, nobody is
home. Or rather, as G.M., Ford, and even G.E. have shown, there is
one face that they are more than willing to show to the consumer:
the financial face.
All three companies make more from financial subsidiaries than
from producing. For instance, in 2004, Ford made a profit of $5
billion from finance, and a loss of $177 million from automobiles[4] , and in 2004 G.M. made
almost $3 billion on finance and lost $89 million on cars[5] . Finance, then, becomes the
third nail in the coffin of U.S. manufacturing, after cheaper wages
and military contracts. Making “profits without production”, the
title of one of Melman’s books, became possible when large
manufacturing corporations turned into large financial firms. In the
1980’s, U.S. Steel used its profits to buy an oil company. Cisco
doesn’t make its products, acting as a combination of finance,
marketing, and design. Dell contracts with companies all over the
world to make its parts, and only performs the final assembly in
Texas. When the dollar collapses and the cost of these outsourced
parts become prohibitive, Dell’s business model will go back to the
garage from whence it came. Manufacturing and myriad other
“high-tech” firms have become the chesire cats of the economy,
losing everything but their brand. But a brand is tied to a
particular economy, and when the American economy goes, so will the
brand.
The U.S. car companies are victims of their own protectionist
lobbying, because car companies are now prevented, via “voluntary
import restraints”, from outsourcing all of their work. Toyota and
Honda are doing just fine in the U.S., but most of the work is for
assembly, a technologically sterile endeavor. The process of
thousands of drones repetitively attaching the same car part over
and over is not the heart of the industrial process, but the end
point. Toyota and Honda make the most sophisticated parts in Japan,
but Ford and G.M. cannot simply create an entire automobile
industrial ecosystem in another country. The automobile ecosystems
have taken a long time to put together, particularly in Germany and
Japan. Their automobile industries are embedded in the wider German
and Japanese industrial ecosystems; G.M. and Ford have to sink or
swim with the American one.
The pension problems of these companies are really the
consequence of their decline, because a company that is growing will
be able to offset the retirement costs of their older employees with
the greater gains that they are supposed to be making with their new
employees. The health care problems, which allegedly add over $1,000
to the price of each car, can be seen as a consequence of the
primitive nature of the U.S. industrial economy. If a national
industrial system should be considered as a whole, than the wider
problems of health care, education, and the infrastructure must be
considered when assessing the performance of any part of the wider
system. All three of these pieces are the poor stepchildren of the
main beneficiaries of the Republican Monarchic Restoration, the
military-industrial complex, the most wealthy taxpayers, and their
partners in corruption. It is on the shoulders of the electorate to
shift from one set to the other; the corporations are too busy
following their noses.
You can contact Jon Rynn directly on his jonrynn.blogspot.com .
You can also find old blog entries and longer articles at
economicreconstruction.com. Please feel free to reach him at
This email address is being protected from spam bots, you need
Javascript enabled to view it
.
[1]
Melman, Seymour. 1956.
Dynamic Factors in Industrial Productivity. Oxford: Blackwell
[2]
Melman defines
productivity of capital by “the total time of machine working, by
stabilizing the rate of working, b reducing defective output and by
minimizing unscheduled interruption”. From Melman, Seymour. 2001.
After Capitalism. New York: A.A. Knopf. p. 425
[3]
Melman, Seymour. 1983.
Profits Without Production. New York: A. A. Knopf. p. 253-259
[4]
Ford 2004 Annual Report,
p. 54
[5]
G.M. 2004 annual report,
p. 44 |